Electoral Reform

Electoral Reform

We desperately need electoral reform in this country.  Canada, along with the United States and Great Britain, cling to an antiquated voting method that is heavily influenced by large companies and the rich, and is designed to concentrate power in a few people.  The only reason Canadian politics has not yet degenerated to the dysfunctional state of American politics is because we have more than two significantly sized political parties.  But without electoral reform this is where we are headed.  Here in Ontario a Progressive Conservative government was elected  (2022) with two thirds of the seats in the legislature, but only 40% of the popular vote.  They have all the power, but 60% of people did not choose them.  What is more, voter turnout was a paltry 43% of eligible voters.  That is at least partly because our system of voting renders many people's ballots completely impotent.  If you are a Green supporter in a riding that mostly supports a Liberal candidate, or a PC supporter in a riding that always goes NDP, what motivation do you have to vote?  Your vote means nothing.

There are better ways of selecting representatives, and most democracies in the world use such methods in their elections.  Some of the best methods are those that deliver proportional representation.  Such systems are designed to yield a legislature that is comprised of a reasonable representation of the preferences of all voters.  For a non-partisan explanation of proportional representation, check out the Fair Vote Canada website.

My suggested electoral system

There are many different voting systems that are considered proportional, and any one of them would be a vast improvement over our current First Past the Post (FPTP) system of elections.  Below is a description of my preferred method; I call it "Personal Mandate Proportional" (PMP).  It is similar to a Mixed Member Proportional (MMP) system,  but what distinguishes PMP from most MMP systems (for example the one used in New Zealand) is that it does not use FPTP in any manner, all elected members serve to represent constituencies, and it requires all elected representatives to personally achieve a significant mandate from voters.  The system works as follows.

Do you see how this system gives meaning to every ballot?  At the local level, the ranked ballot allows voters to provide their preference list; they are not restricted to voting for just one candidate.  Strategic voting, whereby a voter holds their nose and votes for candidate B rather than their preferred candidate C just because they are afraid that if they do not then candidate A will win, is nearly eliminated by this use of a ranked ballot.  A voter such as the one described above would simply rank C then B then A on their ballot.  The fact that there are two ballots allows a voter to distinguish between their local representative and their preferred party.  They could rank the candidate from the party they selected on their second ballot as last on their ranked ballot, if they chose to do so.  And the second ballot for every voter always (unless they select a party that does not reach the threshold) directly influences the final proportions of the parties in the legislature.

DETAILS and MODIFICATIONS:

There are many details to the system described above that could be altered.  

Regardless of the details, any proportional system will serve the needs of Canadians much better than our current FPTP.

Demand electoral reform!  Demand proportional representation!

Allan R. Willms, 2022

Rebuttal of the Toronto Star 2022-06-25 Article "The Saturday Debate: It is finally time for electoral reform in Ontario?" 

On June 25, 2022, the Toronto Star published "The Saturday Debate: It is finally time for electoral reform in Ontario?" In that article, Lydia Miljan argued for the "No" side.  Below is a rebuttal of her arguments.

Lydia's first argument is that low voter turnout could be due to voters being satisfied with the government and having no desire for change, rather than frustration with the electoral system.  Agreed; it could be.  However, I do not suspect that voters today are any more satisfied with their governments than 50 years ago.  Lydia's follow up argument is that there has been substantial variation in voter turnout over the years and that the low turnout in 2022 is not unusual for a "non-change" election.  Lydia then presents some data in a misleading manner, as if to back up her claim that voter turnout has "swung widely from election to election".  The actual data (sourced from Elections Ontario) on voter turnout in Ontario general elections since 1971 are shown in the figure to the right.  Yes, there have been some fluctuations in turnout, but I think "widely" is an exaggeration.  What is more important is the very clear and substantial downward trend.

Lydia's second argument is that there are many variables that influence voter turnout and that "It's not clear how changing the electoral system will influence these factors." There are indeed other factors like the ones she lists: age of the voting population, enthusiasm for change, and political culture.  For the first of these, it is completely clear how changing the electoral system will influence the age of the voting population: either not at all, or, if the voting age is changed, then in a very clear and predictable manner.  As to how changing the electoral system will influence enthusiasm for change and the political culture is, granted, not clear.  My guess is it will influence it for the better.  But regardless, this is not an argument against electoral reform.

Lydia's third argument is that electoral reform cannot truly provide a majority opinion.  Here she is conflating the process of selecting a winner for an individual riding and the idea of proportional representation (PR), which is about producing a representative set of elected officials.  For an individual riding electing one member, most of the time there will never be a majority winning candidate regardless of the system you use, simply because most ridings have more than two candidates who garner substantial support.  She cites the fact that if you use a ranked ballot, where voters provide a ranking of all candidates, that sometimes their second or third choice wins.  Of course.  Under our current first-past-the-post (FPTP) system the person you vote for either wins or loses.  Under a system that uses a ranked ballot, sometimes the person you ranked first will win, sometimes your second rank will win and so on.  How could it be any other way?  I think what she is complaining about is that under a ranked ballot system it is possible that a person with a plurality (more than any other but not a majority) of first place rankings may not be the winner.  Yes, that is true.  It is the point of a ranked ballot.  Unlike the current system, where the only information we gather from voters is their top choice, the use of a ranked ballot allows the voter to convey more information; precisely, it allows them to say what their second and third, etc. choices are.  Although it depends significantly on the electoral system used to select winners from the ranked ballots, such systems try to use the information gathered to select a winner that pleases the most people by some quantitative measure.  Our FPTP system is woefully bad at pleasing the majority of voters.  For example, everyone agrees that if a majority of the electorate favours one candidate then the electoral system should select that candidate as a winner.  Conversely, if a majority of the electorate wants one candidate to lose then the electoral system ought to ensure that candidate does not win.  Yet FPTP regularly fails in this regard.  Reasonable systems using a ranked ballot do not allow this to happen.  Collecting and using more data from voters about their opinions is bound to yield results that are more satisfactory to the populace overall.  But proportional representation is not primarily about how one selects winners for individual ridings; it is about providing a parliament that is representative of the peoples' diverse opinions.

Lydia's fourth argument is that PR systems give areas with high population densities more say in the outcome of elections and that this marginalizes rural voters.  The first part of this statement is true for both PR systems and the first-past-the-post (FPTP) system in use now.  Both give areas with higher density more say, because we as a society believe that representation ought to be based on population not on geographic area.  The second part of the statement, that PR marginalizes rural voters any more than the current system is hard to justify.  The kind of PR system that Lydia is talking about here is one that gives every person a chance to indicate their preferred governing party.  This is the same for rural and urban voters, and gives each voter a say that counts even if the riding they live in elects a local representative of whom they do not approve.  Based on this, it seems that if anything, PR will reduce rural marginalization.

Lydia then makes a classic "look how big this is" feint to try to draw attention away from the even more remarkable opposite.  She points out that 34 ridings in the last election were won by candidates receiving a majority of the votes.  What she failed to point out was that 90 ridings were won by candidates who failed to obtain a majority of the votes.

Lydia's next argument is complete nonsense.  She argues that with PR systems there are more parties that will be able to win seats and therefore parties do not have an incentive before the vote to compromise to differing points of view within the party.  What?  Does she think that with, say 8 political parties able to win at least one seat that we have covered all points of view on any topic?  I can sit down with 20 colleagues at my work place and we can easily come up with 20 differing points of view on just about any subject of importance.  There will be no shortage of a need to compromise within a party just because a few other parties happen to be able to win seats.  What is more, with PR, the parties are required not only to compromise within, but also across party lines.  PR systems generally produce minority parliaments, precisely because the population generally does not give majority support to one party.  What Lydia disparagingly calls "backroom deals after the election" that bypass voters wishes in the process of forming government is in reality discussions and compromise to create a government that adequately reflects the diverse points of view that the voters have expressed.

Finally, Lydia points out that all of the parties except the Greens were unable to increase their number of votes compared to the last election.  Her argument is that the decline in voter turnout was because the parties failed to connect with the population.  I cannot argue against that conclusion, but I point out that if you are a PC supporter in a riding that almost always votes NDP, or a liberal supporter in a riding that almost always votes PC, or a Green supporter in almost any riding, then it is hard to be motivated to vote when you know that your vote will have absolutely no outcome on the election.  That the Greens were able to increase their support in these circumstances indicates that their message is resonating strongly with at least some voters.  PR systems are generally designed to make most people's votes count, that is, have a measurable impact on the formation of the government.  If you know your vote will mean something, it is far more likely you will have motivation to vote.

Allan R. Willms, June, 2022