Leon
Trotsky: On Mexico's Second Six Year Plan
March
14, 1939
A
Program, Not a Plan
[Writings
of Leon Trotsky, Vol 11, 1938-1938, New York ²1974, p. 221-228]
We
are not dealing here with a "plan" in the true sense of the
word. In a society where private property prevails, it is impossible
for the government to direct economic life according to a "plan."
The document contains algebraic formulas but no arithmetic facts. In
other words, it is a general program for governmental activity and
not, strictly speaking, a plan.
Unfortunately,
the authors of the plan do not take into account the limits of
governmental activity in a society where the means of production,
including the land, are not nationalized. They have apparently taken
the Five Year Plans of the USSR as a model and often use the same
phraseology, without taking into account the fundamental differences
in social structures. It is for this reason, as we shall see later,
that the algebraic formulas are often a means for passing over the
most burning questions of Mexican life while taking solace in
perspectives borrowed from the reports and official statements of the
USSR.
Reform
of the State Machinery
The
document starts off, in paragraph two, with a proposal for
instituting "a technical body subordinate to the president"
to carry out the Six Year Plan. This proposal, despite its rather
secondary, administrative nature, seems to contain a fundamental
error. Governmental action in carrying out the plan cannot develop
within the scope of governmental action pure and simple.
Superimposing on the government a "technical body," whose
task is neither more nor less than transforming the entire national
economy, would mean creating a "super-government" alongside
the regular government, i.e., administrative chaos.
A
more realistic proposal, based on the experience of various countries
during the war as well as on the experience of the USSR, would be to
create a limited government committee composed of the heads of the
ministries most directly involved in the plan and placed under the
direction of the president or his immediate representative. In this
case, general governmental activity along with the activity that
concerns the plan would be concentrated in the same hands, and
useless repetition — this bureaucratic scourge — would be
minimized as far as possible.
Paragraph
three proposes "functional participation of the organized
sectors of the country's population" in various organs of the
government. This formulation is extremely vague and allows all sorts
of possible interpretations. We hasten to point out first of all that
this proposal threatens to incorporate a bureaucratic hierarchy of
the unions, etc., without precise delimitation, into the bureaucratic
hierarchy of the state (nearly impossible to accomplish in practice)
thereby restraining the regular activity of the organs of state and
creating an almost insurmountable state of confusion.
Mexico’s
Foreign Policy
In
this most important domain, the plan rests on generalities. It
doesn't name a single country, and even within the realm of
generalities it points to a line of conduct that should be considered
fundamentally wrong.
In
the name of "democracy and liberty," the plan proposes to
improve the relations Mexico currently has with "Latin American
nations and those nations on all continents that have a democratic
form of government." We immediately run into an obvious
contradiction. For the Americas the policy is to enter into friendly
relations will all nations, whatever the nature of their internal
regimes, while for the other continents the prescription is for
friendly relations exclusively with the so-called "democratic"
countries. The plan does not indicate how to develop increasingly
friendly relations with "democratic" England, which treats
Mexico like a fief for its oil interests. Is it necessary to beg
London's pardon and immediately reestablish diplomatic relations in
the name of "democracy and liberty"? Moreover, in the
struggle developing at the present time between the "democratic"
mother country of 45
million inhabitants and India, deprived of democracy but with a
population of 370 million people, to which side should Mexico extend
its positive friendship in order to solidly reinforce its world
position? The organic weakness of the plan lies in dissolving the
opposition between oppressor and oppressed nations into the abstract
concept of democracy. This division is far more profound and bears
far more weight than the division of the slaveholders' camp into
democratic and fascist nations.
The
expropriation of the oil companies and the resolute attitude of the
Mexican government toward England have greatly diminished "sympathy"
toward Mexico in that capitalist "democracy"; but at the
same time, these acts have enormously elevated Mexico's prestige in
India and in all the colonies and oppressed nations. The only
conclusion to draw is that a semicolonial country should not allow
itself to be fooled by the democratic form of its actual or potential
oppressors.
Mexico
cannot safeguard and develop its independence and assure its future
in any other way than by
taking advantage of the antagonisms and conflicts between the
imperialist slaveholders
without identifying with one side or the other, and by assuring
itself of the esteem and support of the enslaved nations and the
oppressed masses in general.
Agrarian
Reform
This
part of the program, the most important part for Mexican life, is
based not on an analysis of the needs of the country, but rather on
some general formula borrowed from the vocabulary of the USSR and
very badly adapted to national realities.
Paragraph
eight states: "Restitutions, grants, and extensions of land to
the peasant communities will proceed at a rate not slower than that
of the years 1935-38." At the same time, point (c) of paragraph
thirteen states: "Organization of the collective exploitation of
all common public lands” for the next six years. These two
dimensions of the program are not at all coordinated. They are simply
superimposed, one upon the other.
What
is the main question in Mexico today? Agrarian reform, or the
democratic
agrarian revolution;
that is, the life of the peasants is characterized by a massive
accumulation of the holdovers of feudal property forms and the
relations and traditions of slavery. It is necessary to courageously
and definitively liquidate these holdovers from medieval barbarism
with the aid of the peasants themselves. The large parasitic or
semi-parasitic landed proprietors, the economic and political
domination of the landowners over the peasants, forced agricultural
labor, the quasi-patriarchal sharecropping system, which is
fundamentally equivalent to slavery – these are the things that
must be definitively liquidated in the shortest possible time. Now,
the program does not even call for the completion of this task, which
is essential to the democratic revolution, within the next six years;
but at the same time it does call for the complete collectivization
of the common lands in the same period of time. This is a complete
inconsistency, which can lead to the most dire consequences,
economic, social, and political.
"Complete
Collectivization”
A.
Collectivization means the replacement of small-scale rural
agriculture by large-scale agriculture. This change is only
advantageous if highly developed technology adequate to the tasks of
large-scale agriculture exists. This means that the proposed rate of
collectivization should be adapted to the development of industry, of
production of farm machinery, fertilizer, etc.
B.
But technology alone is not sufficient. The peasants themselves must
accept collectivization, that is, they must understand the advantages
on the basis of their own experience or that of others.
C.
Finally, the human material, or at least a large part of it, must be
educated and prepared for the economic and technical management of
the common lands.
The
plan itself says in paragraph fifteen that it is necessary to count
on "peasants who are properly educated” and calls for the
creation of a sufficient number of schools, especially agricultural
schools. If we allow that such schools will be established in
sufficient number during the next six years, it is clear that the
necessary personnel will not be ready till quite some time later.
Collectivizing ignorance and misery by means of state compulsion
would not mean advancing agriculture, but rather would inevitably
lead to forcing the peasants into the camp of the reaction.
The
agrarian revolution must be completed within six years in order for
the country to be in a position to advance toward the goal of
collectivization on this foundation, very carefully, without
compulsion, and with a very sympathetic attitude toward the
peasantry.
The
Example of the USSR
The
USSR went through not only a bourgeois democratic revolution, but a
proletarian revolution as well. The Russian peasants, although very
poor, were not as poor as the Mexican peasants. Soviet industry was
considerably more developed. Nevertheless, after the nationalization
of the land, i.e., the complete agrarian democratic revolution, for
many long years the collectivized sector of agriculture formed only a
tiny percentage of the agricultural economy in relation to the
individual peasant economy. It is true that twelve years after the
abolition of the latifundia, etc., the ruling bureaucracy passed over
to "complete collectivization" for reasons that we do not
need to go into here. The results are well known. Agricultural
production fell off by half, the peasants revolted, tens of millions
died as the result of terrible famines. The bureaucracy was forced to
partially reestablish private agriculture. Nationalized industry had
to produce hundreds of thousands of tractors and farm machines for
the kolkhozes to begin making progress. Imitating these methods in
Mexico would mean heading for disaster. It is necessary to complete
the democratic revolution by giving the land, all the land, to the
peasants. On the basis of this established conquest the peasants must
be given an unlimited period to reflect, compare, experiment with
different methods of agriculture. They must be aided, technically and
financially, but not compelled. In short, it is necessary to finish
the work of Emiliano Zapata and not to superimpose on him the methods
of Joseph Stalin.
Agricultural
Credit.
The
entire agrarian part of the program is deformed by a false
perspective that tries to take the third or fourth step before the
first step is completed. This deformation of perspective is
particularly flagrant with regard to the question of credit.
Paragraph sixteen, point (d) calls for all agricultural credit to be
extended to the common lands "abandoning the aim of maintaining
the economy of small agricultural property." That the state
should accord financial privileges to voluntary collectives goes
without saying. But proportions must be maintained. The collective
enterprises must be kept viable, but the small individual farms must
continue to survive and grow as well during the historical period
necessary to accomplish "complete collectivization"; and
this period may entail several decades.
If
methods of compulsion are used, this will only produce collectives
that exist at state expense, while lowering the general level of
agriculture and impoverishing the country.
The
Industrialization of the Country
In
this area the program becomes extremely vague and abstract. In order
to collectivize the common lands in six years an enormous outlay for
the production of farm machinery, fertilizer, railroads, and industry
in general would be necessary. And all of this immediately, because a
certain technological development, at least on an elementary level,
should precede collectivization and not follow it. Where will the
necessary means come from? The plan is silent on this point except
for a few sentences about the advantages of domestic loans over
foreign loans. But the country is poor. It needs foreign capital.
This thorny problem is treated only to the extent that the program
does not insist on the cancellation of the foreign debt. And that is
all.
It
is true that the realization of the democratic agrarian revolution,
i.e., handing over all the arable land to the peasantry, would
increase the capacity of the domestic market in a relatively short
time; but despite all that, the rate of industrialization would be
very slow. Considerable international capital is seeking areas of
investment at the present time, even where only a modest (but sure)
return is possible. Turning one's back on foreign capital and
speaking of collectivization and industrialization is mere
intoxication with words.
The
reactionaries are wrong when they say that the expropriation of the
oil companies has made the influx of new capital impossible. The
government defends the vital resources of the country, but at the
same time it can grant industrial concessions, above all in the form
of mixed corporations, i e., enterprises in which the government
participates (holding 10 percent, 25 percent, 51 percent of the
stock, according to the circumstances ) and writes into the contracts
the option of buying out the rest of the stock after a certain period
of time. This government participation would have the advantage of
educating native technical and administrative personnel in
collaboration with the best engineers and organizers of other
countries. The period fixed in the contract before the optional
buying out of the enterprise would create the necessary confidence
among capital investors. The rate of industrialization would be
accelerated.
State
Capitalism
The
authors of the program wish to completely construct state capitalism
within a period of six years. But nationalizing existing enterprises
is one thing; creating new ones with limited means on virgin soil is
another.
History
knows only one example of an industry created under state supervision
— the USSR. But,
a)
a socialist revolution was necessary;
b)
the industrial heritage of the past played an important role,
c)
the public debt was canceled (1. 5
billion pesos a year).
Despite
all these advantages the industrial reconstruction of the country was
begun with the granting of concessions. Lenin accorded great
importance to these concessions for the economic development of the
country and for the technical and administrative education of Soviet
personnel. There has been no socialist revolution in Mexico. The
international situation does not even allow the cancellation of the
public debt. The country, we repeat, is poor. Under such conditions
it would be almost suicidal to close the doors to foreign capital.
To
construct state capitalism, capital is necessary.
The
Unions
Paragraph
ninety-six speaks quite correctly about the necessity to "protect
the working class more effectively than is the case today." It
would only be necessary to add: "It is necessary to protect the
working class not only against the excesses of capitalist
exploitation but against the abuses of the labor bureaucracy as
well."
The
program has a lot to say about democracy and the workers'
organizations, which are the essential base of this democracy. This
would be absolutely correct if the unions were themselves democratic
and not totalitarian. A democratic regime in the union should assure
the workers control over their own bureaucracy and thus eliminate the
most flagrant abuses. The strictest accountability of the unions
should be a public affair.
★ ★ ★
These
notes may seem imbued with a very moderate, almost conservative
spirit in comparison to the high-flown, but, alas, empty,
formulations of the program. We believe, however, that our point of
view is more realistic and at the same time more revolutionary. The
central point of the program is the agrarian question. It is a
thousand times easier to preach total collectivization in a vacuum
than to carry out with an iron hand the total elimination of feudal
remnants in the countryside. This cleansing operation would truly be
an excellent program for the next six years. The peasantry would
understand such a program, set down in ten lines, and accept it much
more warmly than this vague and verbose translation of the official
documents of the Kremlin.